
One of the most often stated arguments in favor of government intervention in American healthcare are the enormous costs paid by consumers in the United States in comparison to the rest of the Western world. Sadly what is left out of this analysis is a mathematical and economic understanding of the difference in drug prices between nations. With the recent nomination of an avowed socialist in New York, now is as good a time as any to discuss conservative policy proposals to counter the inevitable siren-song of socialized medicine. This essay will attempt to provide a basic introduction to the concept that a comparison between national healthcare expenditures is flawed and should result in altering the goals (and policies for achieving those goals) of government intervention.
American spending on healthcare is the topic of constant hand wringing by political do-gooders in Washington and their allies around the country. Americans, we are told, are being screwed out of their hard earned money by greedy CEOs and insurance companies. Leftists say we need to regulate prices and subsidize the sick with the healthy in order to do reduce spending the way Europeans and Canadians do. While I cannot prove that American costs would lower to those of our Western counterparts (or that theirs would rise to be the same as ours), I can show that Western social democracies leverage American spending to their benefit (in much the same way they do with NATO). In effect Americans subsidize the cost of European and Canadian healthcare in such a way that comparing international prices results in, at best, misleading information and, at worst, a misguided path that ends in the total elimination of private medical research.
Medical innovations do not happen accidentally. Research and development of new drugs is an enormous cost ranging from, on average, roughly $800 million to $1.2 billion.[1] The only method by which pharmaceutical companies can bear such enormous costs is by passing the expense of R&D on to the consumer. This should be patently obvious to anyone who has ever purchased cutting edge technology–the cost of a mobile phone in 1982 was $3995 (the price would be more than double that if you calculate for inflation).[2] Paying enormous prices while the technology was in its infancy has allowed us to live in a world where we have more computing power in our pockets than the computers that landed astronauts on the moon while costing less than 10% of 1982 mobile phone prices, inflation adjusted.
The process of funding medical advancement is no different. A pharmaceutical company that invests a billion dollars into research relies on market prices that make such investments a reasonable financial decision in order to finance further innovation. Opportunity cost of investing in R&D must be taken into consideration. For those unfamiliar, opportunity cost is the cost incurred by placing finite resources (time, money, etc.) in one venture rather than another. When I spend $500 on cigars in a year I forgo the returns I could have made by investing that money in my retirement account. The rational decision maker must enjoy the cigars more than the cost of the cigars multiplied by the growth rate compounded annually. So if you assume a 10% per annum growth rate, I need to value the cigars more than $550 a year from now, and $605 two years from now. Clearly I’m not spending my money wisely, but I digress. A company investing in R&D must, in order to justify the costs, expect long term return on investment (ROI) to be greater than the alternative uses for their capital.
This is all to say that when a new drug is developed the cost of the drug is passed along to consumers. In order to turn a profit the average price of the new drug must be greater than the average total cost (ATC) as defined by the following equation where C represents cost and Q represents quantity[3]:
It should be noted that this is different from marginal cost (MC) in that MC is the change in cost relative to the change in quantity without regard to fixed costs (MC being a differential equation and the constant disappears following differentiation). Often the cost of producing additional units of any good rise due to situations such as the necessity of purchasing additional equipment in order to meet increased production requirements. For the sake of simplicity we will assume that our hypothetical pharmaceutical company can purchase additional factories a zero cost. This actually can be useful in our understanding as long term outcomes can treat additional infrastructure expenses as fixed costs. Finally, from a practical actuarial perspective, ATC is a far more useful business metric than that of MC (although both obviously have different uses).
How does this all relate to the difference between American healthcare prices and those of Western social democracies? American consumers of healthcare pay market prices, although they primarily deal with pharmaceutical oligopolies rather than the ideal market situation of multiple buyers and multiple sellers. As such, the companies producing the goods can sell at the highest price that the market is willing to bear; the price at which the average consumer values the good is equal to the price of the good. Conversely, Western social democracies utilizing a single payer system can demand prices of producers far lower than what the market would otherwise predict. Pharmaceutical companies, as they have the American market to recoup their R&D costs, evaluate the minimum price they are willing to sell at to single payer systems through the following equation:
The result is that, in the long run, the minimum price that a producer will accept is the cost of producing another unit of the drug rather than the ATC.[4] This is the leverage that single payer systems utilize to reduce the prices they pay. But given that the average price worldwide of the good sold must remain higher than the ATC, the consumers in the United States end up being required by pharmaceutical companies to pay higher prices to offset the worldwide prices which may be lower than the ATC. This is American subsidization of research, plain and simple. It’s not just me saying this–every[5] single[6] one[7] of[8] these[9] articles[10] refers[11] to it as subsidization (and that’s just the front page of Google).
This difference in drug prices has a large impact on the overall price of healthcare in the United States. A 2003 study found that the difference in price of healthcare is primarily due to the higher price of health goods and services.[12] With this information it should be plainly obvious that comparing American healthcare costs to those of Western social democracies with the intention of attempting to mimic the cost-saving measure of other countries is folly without the ability to predict where prices would be without American subsidies.
There is one thing that is undeniably true: if American healthcare consumers suddenly started paying the same prices as their European and Canadian counterparts the world’s private medical research would come to a screeching halt. This should give pause to any American single payer advocate (I’m looking at you, hippies).
So what policy suggestions can be made to rectify the situation? There is no magic pill (pun totally intended) to solve all our problems regarding medical spending but we can start by getting accurate numbers. Any bill aimed at improving healthcare costs must include the requirement for pharmaceutical companies, both foreign and domestic, to treat American consumers with “Most Favored Nation” status. This means that companies who wish to do business within the United States may not charge more than their lowest price abroad. That forces companies who do not wish to lose access to the wealthiest nation in the world’s consumer base to raise their prices abroad, lower their prices within the United States, or a combination of both.
Again, this does not necessarily solve the problem but we cannot solve something for which we have inaccurate information.
QED, y’all.
Matt Wiltshire is a Republican campaign veteran. He was Rick Walker’s campaign manager during the CD2 primary and Jeff Williams’ during the runoff for JP5, Place 2.
[1]Elizabeth Whitman, “How The US Subsidizes Cheap Drugs For Europe,” http://www.ibtimes.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[2] Josh Smith, “History of Cellphones: Shrinking Sizes and Prices [Infographic],” http://www.gottabemobile.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[3] I should admit that it has been many years since I took formal economics or calculus classes–so while my equations might be slightly off, the principle should be apparent enough.
[4] One obvious flaw in the equation is that no producer plans on producing infinite units of a good. The actuarial calculations vary from company to company and will take into account the expected lifespan of a product which is a variable I am not qualified to make any guess at.
[5] Ezra Klein, “Why an MRI costs $1,080 in America and $280 in France,” https://www.washingtonpost.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[6] Elizabeth Whitman, “How The US Subsidizes Cheap Drugs For Europe,” http://www.ibtimes.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[7] Beth Kowitt, “How the U.S. Subsidizes Europe’s Health Care Costs,” http://fortune.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[8] Paul Soloman, “Do Other Countries Piggyback On U.S. Healthcare Spending?,” http://www.pbs.org, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[9] Raymond Raad, Glen Whitman, “Bending the Productivity Curve: Why America Leads the World in Medical Innovation,” https://www.cato.org, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[10] Megan McArdle, “U.S. Consumers Foot the Bill for Cheap Drugs in Europe and Canada,” https://www.bloomberg.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[11] Denver Nicks, “This Is Why the U.S. Pays More for Prescription Drugs Than Other Countries,” http://time.com, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
[12] Gerald F. Anderson, Peter S. Hussey, Varduhi Petrosyan, Uwe E. Reinhardt, “It’s The Prices, Stupid: Why The United States Is So Different From Other Countries,” http://content.healthaffairs.org, (Accessed February 5, 2017)
Setting aside data showing that CEOs of “non-profit” hospitals make incredible salaries, the author is right that Americans are being ripped off to subsidize low drug prices in Canada, Western Europe and other places. i have a friend who has to take a drug daily. The cost difference is so great that if she could get a 90-day supply rather than a 60-day supply in France, she could save enough money to have a week in Paris every quarter (including air fare).
Congress has denied Medicare the ability to negotiate drug prices with drug companies even though experience shows that the Veterans Administration can and does save millions by negotiating prices. It’s the Big Pharma lobby.
They spend millions lobbying and making campaign contributions to members of Congress. To a great extent, Big Pharma owns congressional leadership and influential members.
President Trump just finished a NATO summit in which he accused our allies of getting a free ride for defense on the backs of the US taxpayer. While the president’s direct comparison of percentage of gross national product spent on defense is misleading because the US has worldwide defense commitments while most NATO states have interests only in Europe, he’s basically right.
But, why are the president and the administration basically silent on high drug prices paid by US consumers are subsidizing European consumers?
Remember what Deep Throat said: Follow the money.
I was always curious as to why one could walk across the border and buy the same drugs sold here for pennies on the dollar.
@Tom – In response to “But, why are the president and the administration basically silent on high drug prices paid by US consumers are subsidizing European consumers?” Actually, Trump has been far from silent regarding this and just recently criticized Pfizer who announced another price hike starting July. On July 9th, Trump tweeted “Pfizer & others should be ashamed that they have raised drug prices for no reason. They are merely taking advantage of the poor & others unable to defend themselves, while at the same time giving bargain basement prices to other countries in Europe & elsewhere. We will respond!” After his criticism, Pfizer’s stock continued to increase throughout the day and the following day. Late July 10th, Pfizer announced a reversal on the price increases they had announced for July and rollbacks of those increases which had already begun until either the end of the year or the administration implements a plan to decrease the cost of medicines in the U.S. – whichever comes first. Once Pfizer announced the price rollback, their stock price went down that evening in the after-market trading and the next day. Then it rebounded a bit – probably because after the initial market knee jerk reaction, buyers decided that Pfizer would still turn a hefty profit.
Another issue the administration is not silent on regarding big pharma is their roll (the blame doesn’t lie solely with them but they are part of the big picture. China plays a big role in dumpinig deadly fentanyl or mimics into our streets but people turn to this after they already have an addiction a lot of times developed via over prescribed pain killers) in increasing opiate addiction in this country.
https://www.nytimes.com/2018/04/17/us/politics/jeff-sessions-opioids-dea.html
http://www.newsweek.com/jeff-sessions-going-after-big-pharma-opioid-manufacturers-822857
I’ll add as a note to the article above. Not only does the U.S. subsidize other countries pharmaceutical purchases via higher prices. To add insult to injury, we further subsidize it in the form of extensive research grants which fund the research that trains post-doctoral and graduate students who eventually then go work for the pharmaceutical companies. The amounts the pharmacy companies give as research grants to university departments involved with pharmaceutical research is very small in comparison to what the U.S. government provides. So in part the tax payers also pay to train the future employees of the pharmaceutical companies via research funding. Meanwhile, Canadian and European citizens smugly criticize the wealthy U.S. for not doing more for their citizens while their medical welfare programs are in part subsidized by the U.S.